Median voter theorem

In political science and social choice, Black's median voter theorem says that if voters and candidates are distributed along a political spectrum, any Condorcet consistent voting method will elect the candidate preferred by the median voter.[1] The median voter theorem thus shows that under a realistic model of voter behavior, Arrow's theorem does not apply, and rational choice is possible for societies. The theorem was first derived by Duncan Black in 1948,[2] and independently by Kenneth Arrow.

Similar median voter theorems exist for rules like score voting and approval voting[3][4] when voters are either strategic and informed or if voters' ratings of candidates fall linearly with ideological distance.

An immediate consequence of Black's theorem, sometimes called the Hotelling-Downs median voter theorem, is that if the conditions for Black's theorem hold, politicians who only care about winning the election will adopt the same position as the median voter.[5][6][7] However, this strategic convergence only occurs in voting systems that actually satisfy the median voter property (see below).[8][9][10]

  1. ^ P. Dasgupta and E. Maskin, "The fairest vote of all" (2004); "On the Robustness of Majority Rule" (2008).
  2. ^ Black, Duncan (1948-02-01). "On the Rationale of Group Decision-making". Journal of Political Economy. 56 (1): 23–34. doi:10.1086/256633. ISSN 0022-3808. S2CID 153953456.
  3. ^ Cox, Gary W. (1985). "Electoral Equilibrium under Approval Voting". American Journal of Political Science. 29 (1): 112–118. doi:10.2307/2111214. ISSN 0092-5853. JSTOR 2111214.
  4. ^ Myerson, Roger B.; Weber, Robert J. (March 1993). "A Theory of Voting Equilibria". American Political Science Review. 87 (1): 102–114. doi:10.2307/2938959. hdl:10419/221141. ISSN 1537-5943. JSTOR 2938959.
  5. ^ Holcombe, Randall G. (2006). Public Sector Economics: The Role of Government in the American Economy. Pearson Education. p. 155. ISBN 9780131450424.
  6. ^ Hotelling, Harold (1929). "Stability in Competition". The Economic Journal. 39 (153): 41–57. doi:10.2307/2224214. JSTOR 2224214.
  7. ^ Anthony Downs, "An Economic Theory of Democracy" (1957).
  8. ^ McGann, Anthony J.; Koetzle, William; Grofman, Bernard (2002). "How an Ideologically Concentrated Minority Can Trump a Dispersed Majority: Nonmedian Voter Results for Plurality, Run-off, and Sequential Elimination Elections". American Journal of Political Science. 46 (1): 134–147. doi:10.2307/3088418. ISSN 0092-5853.
  9. ^ Myerson, Roger B.; Weber, Robert J. (March 1993). "A Theory of Voting Equilibria". American Political Science Review. 87 (1): 102–114. doi:10.2307/2938959. hdl:10419/221141. ISSN 1537-5943. JSTOR 2938959.
  10. ^ Mussel, Johanan D.; Schlechta, Henry (2023-07-21). "Australia: No party convergence where we would most expect it". Party Politics. 30 (6): 1040–1050. doi:10.1177/13540688231189363. ISSN 1354-0688.

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia · View on Wikipedia

Developed by Nelliwinne