Theorem in political science
In political science and social choice , Black's median voter theorem says that if voters and candidates are distributed along a political spectrum , any Condorcet consistent voting method will elect the candidate preferred by the median voter.[ 1] The median voter theorem thus shows that under a realistic model of voter behavior, Arrow's theorem does not apply, and rational choice is possible for societies. The theorem was first derived by Duncan Black in 1948,[ 2] and independently by Kenneth Arrow .
Similar median voter theorems exist for rules like score voting and approval voting [ 3] [ 4] when voters are either strategic and informed or if voters' ratings of candidates fall linearly with ideological distance .
An immediate consequence of Black's theorem, sometimes called the Hotelling-Downs median voter theorem , is that if the conditions for Black's theorem hold, politicians who only care about winning the election will adopt the same position as the median voter.[ 5] [ 6] [ 7] However, this strategic convergence only occurs in voting systems that actually satisfy the median voter property (see below ).[ 8] [ 9] [ 10]
^ P. Dasgupta and E. Maskin, "The fairest vote of all" (2004); "On the Robustness of Majority Rule" (2008).
^ Black, Duncan (1948-02-01). "On the Rationale of Group Decision-making" . Journal of Political Economy . 56 (1): 23– 34. doi :10.1086/256633 . ISSN 0022-3808 . S2CID 153953456 .
^ Cox, Gary W. (1985). "Electoral Equilibrium under Approval Voting" . American Journal of Political Science . 29 (1): 112– 118. doi :10.2307/2111214 . ISSN 0092-5853 . JSTOR 2111214 .
^ Myerson, Roger B.; Weber, Robert J. (March 1993). "A Theory of Voting Equilibria" . American Political Science Review . 87 (1): 102– 114. doi :10.2307/2938959 . hdl :10419/221141 . ISSN 1537-5943 . JSTOR 2938959 .
^ Holcombe, Randall G. (2006). Public Sector Economics: The Role of Government in the American Economy . Pearson Education. p. 155. ISBN 9780131450424 .
^ Hotelling, Harold (1929). "Stability in Competition". The Economic Journal . 39 (153): 41– 57. doi :10.2307/2224214 . JSTOR 2224214 .
^ Anthony Downs, "An Economic Theory of Democracy " (1957).
^ McGann, Anthony J.; Koetzle, William; Grofman, Bernard (2002). "How an Ideologically Concentrated Minority Can Trump a Dispersed Majority: Nonmedian Voter Results for Plurality, Run-off, and Sequential Elimination Elections" . American Journal of Political Science . 46 (1): 134– 147. doi :10.2307/3088418 . ISSN 0092-5853 .
^ Myerson, Roger B.; Weber, Robert J. (March 1993). "A Theory of Voting Equilibria" . American Political Science Review . 87 (1): 102– 114. doi :10.2307/2938959 . hdl :10419/221141 . ISSN 1537-5943 . JSTOR 2938959 .
^ Mussel, Johanan D.; Schlechta, Henry (2023-07-21). "Australia: No party convergence where we would most expect it" . Party Politics . 30 (6): 1040– 1050. doi :10.1177/13540688231189363 . ISSN 1354-0688 .